We know that
specialisation occurs at all levels in the global economy (individual
division of labour, firms, regions and countries).
If we assume
there are only two counties in the world, England and France, each with the
same quantity of resources, and they produce only two goods, bread and jam.
England and
France devote half of their resources to the production of each of the goods.
We can see from the table below that with a year’s
worth of labour in England can produce more bread and jam than in France.
England therefore has an absolute advantage in the production of bread and
jam.
|
Bread
(units)
|
Jam
(units)
|
England
|
30
|
15
|
France
|
5
|
10
|
World
Total
|
|
|
England is
six times as efficient in bread production, but only 50% more efficient in
jam production.
If
France wishes to produce an extra unit of jam it has to give up half a unit
of bread, however if England wishes to produce an extra unit of jam it must
give up two units of bread. A
country’s comparative advantage lies in the good that it can produce
relatively cheaply, i.e. at a lower opportunity cost than its trading
partner.
England
(which has an absolute advantage in both commodities) therefore has a
comparative advantage in bread production, whereas France has a comparative
advantage in jam production.
If each
country specialises completely in the good that they have a comparative
advantage in, the production totals will be:
|
Bread
(units)
|
Jam
(units)
|
England
|
60
|
0
|
France
|
0
|
20
|
World
Total
|
|
|
Compared to
the earlier situation without specialisation and trade, there has been a gain
of 25 units of bread, but a fall of 5 units of jam.
We cannot say for sure whether or not there has been a welfare gain as
the amount of jam has fallen and we do not know what value consumers place on
jam.
In order to
demonstrate a welfare gain, a situation must be devised where at least as
much of one good and more of another results from specialisation and trade.
We obtain this result, by allowing England to devote one sixth of its
resources to jam production, giving production totals that are shown
overleaf:
|
Bread
(units)
|
Jam
(units)
|
England
|
50
|
5
|
France
|
0
|
20
|
World
Total
|
|
|
There are a
number of assumptions that we have to make when looking at the above example
of comparative advantage:
• There
are no transport costs.
• Costs
are constant, therefore there are no economies of scale.
• There
are only two economies producing goods.
• Goods
are homogeneous in different countries.
• Factors
of production are completely mobile.
• There
are no tariffs or other trade barriers.
• There is
perfect knowledge.
We can find
analogies in terms of individuals specialising in different tasks.
Some lawyers are better typists than their secretaries, but the
secretaries do all of the typing. The
lawyer has an absolute advantage in both practising law and typing, but the
secretary has a comparative advantage in typing.
This is
because the opportunity cost of the lawyer doing an hours typing is far
higher than that of the secretary, therefore it makes sense for the secretary
to type and allow the lawyer to practice law.
Notes on the
internet
Benefits of Trade
Benefits of Trade and Protectionism
|